Notes

Scratch Notes for the Seminar Paper

Sonneberg

Sonneberg: - Germany’s first AfD district administrator (Landrat) - Robert Sesselmann - prevails in run-off election against conservative CDU - 52.8% to 47.2%

shocking to political establishment, international coverage

Sonneberg also: district with the highest proportion of minimum wage earners in DE - 2022 increase in minimum wage to 12 euros - 44% of Sonneberg residents benefited from this - the highest in Germany

Research Question: What is the connection between minimum wage and populism?

additional about Sonneberg:

  • thüringenweit höchste Industriedichte
  • schon damals viele Arbeiter, die erst rot und dann NS gewählt haben (Wiki)
  • Thüringen erste NSDAP Regierungsbeteiligung
  • auch genannt SPielzeugstadt
  • Wahlergebnisse hsitorisch S.90
    • Stadt mit meisten NSDAP Stimmen 1929

Literature

Overview Papers Economic Drivers

Fischer and Meister (2023) (DIW)

  • trade exposure (globalization)
  • financial crises
    • austerity measures
    • unfair perception of bailouts
  • MIgration
    • economic fears (must not be rational)
    • sudden influxes of many = more right wing
  • inequality
    • perception of unfairness
    • low intergenerail mobility

another overview by Guriev and Papaioannou (2022)

  • trade
    • exposure to low wage industrial competition
    • especially in rural regions (cities could protect from impacts with service industry)
  • economic crisis
    • austerity
    • redistribution
  • cultural backlash
  • immigration
    • shock immigration of 2015 syrian refugee crisis
    • higher perception than reality
  • also emigration (esp. eastern europe)
    • good ground for populist vote of the remaining

Economic Drivers

Literature on economic drivers presented above, but on german / european district level

Gabriel, Klein, and Pessoa (2023)

regional Database on political costs of austerity

  • fiscal austeritiy =>
    • higher share for extreme parties
    • lower vote turnout
    • 1% reduction => 3% increase vote
  • austerity driven recession => even more
    • lower trust in government
    • special of just recession

Dippel et al. (2022) : Trade in Germany Populist

  • case study germany Effect of Trade on Workers and Votes
  • low skilled manufacturing workers = votes responsive to trade exposure
  • level of Landkreise in Germany
  • have interesting dataset on trade exposure in the counties

Alesina, Stantcheva, and Teso (2018)

  • lower intergenerational mobility
  • higher rpreference for redistributional policy
  • differences in perception

Sociodemographic Driver Populism

Pickel (2019): Sozialstrukturelle Analyse

  • self identify class: lower class & working class & middle class
    • real: mostly workers and Facharbeiter
    • also some lower state servants (Beamte)
  • no age / income differences to general population

Hövermann (2023): Sociodemografic Factors and Work

  • more temporary workers (befristet)
  • bad working conditions = lower esteem of work
  • uncontempt with current wage
  • lower share of workers council (Betriebsrat)

Cultural Drivers

  • not only economic explanations, also cultural / identity politics
  • activated by economic shocks

Cantoni, Hagemeister, and Westcott (2019)

  • municipalities with nazi history 1933 = stonger support today
  • AfD = party platofrm with low social stigma

position & status

Kurer and Staalduinen (2022) Status Discrodance

  • calculated expected status based on parents occupation
  • and difference to achieved status in reality
  • especially men and eastern german high discordance

also Brian Burgoon et al. (2019)

  • positional deprivation = income growth relative to other influences vote
  • slow = retreat from mainstream parties = feeling of losing out

Literature on Minimum Wage and Politics

Zavodny (2020)

  • political economy of minimum wages
  • focuses mostly on height of MW in different countries
    • influencing factors on it

focus more general on labor market policies in general and support for populist vote Bergman (2022)

  • loss of status as driver

Data

Vote Share AfD: Bundeswahlleiter

  • calculated for the different Landkreise, not Wahlbezirke
  • Parliament Election on 09/2021

Minimum Wage: Wirtschaft- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut (Hans Böckler Stiftung)

based on:

  • BA Arbeit
  • Destatis
  • SOEP

=> extrapolated by WSI

  • “sozialversicherungspflichtig beschäftigte” in district
  • part / full time, not MiniJob
  • projected for 01/10/2022

additional Data

  • Regionalstatistik des Bundes und der Länder
  • Regionatlas for Geodata

Method

Linear Regressio with OLS Estimator

\[ \text{afd}_k = \beta_0 + \beta_1 \times \text{min}_k + \epsilon \]

  • \(\text{afd}_k\) AfD Vote Share in Landkreis \(k\)
  • \(\text{min}_k\) Share of Minimum Wage Recipients in Landkreis \(k\)
  • \(\beta_0\) Intercept
  • \(\beta_1\) Slope
  • \(\epsilon\) Error

Results

basic Model

  • Estimated Coefficient = 0.7
  • statistically significant
  • R2 = 0.61

=> 1% increase in MW recipoients => 0.7% increase in AfD share

Model with Eastern German Dummy

  • as visible on electoral Maps = eastern Germany more right wing vote share
  • dummy for ost (1 = eastern, 0 = not)
  • coefficient lower = 0.3
  • but still significant
  • R2 increase = 0.74

additional controls

  • not significant in all specificiations
  • do not change R2 much
  • no real impact
  • unemployment rate,
  • log GPD per Cap
  • log pop. density
  • foreigners rate
  • age

Test for Wahlergebnis of left poplist party (Die LINKE)

  • some way yes
  • but not really significant
  • as described by Piketty = left today not really “abgehängte”

Discussion

Populism = multicausal, not only socioeconomic, but also sociodemographic, cultural, …

my argument:

Minimum Wage is one of the channels translating abstract phenonema to populist vote:

phenomena / factors (from literature):

  • financial crisis
  • austeritiy
  • trade exposure

lead to: Minimum Wage / Low Wage sector

equals: - lack of mobility - status discordance - general disappointment (inequality etc)

=> leads to populist voting

factors:

  • financial crisis
    • shwon by Nau and Soener (2019)
    • crisis hits low income and middle income
    • creates income precarity
    • higher risk for insecuritry for all groups
  • austerity
  • trade exposure
    • as shown by Utar (2018)
    • manufacturing workers => instable low wage service jobs

channels

  • lack of mobility
    • Dodin et al. (2021)] adn (Alesina, Stantcheva, and Teso 2018)
    • if high share of MW = not many higher paying jobs
    • esp. eastern germans = not many high earning positions
    • future pessimism = easier for populists
  • status discordancy Kurer and Staalduinen (2022)
    • MW = lowest status possible (except unemployed)
    • comparison to parent generation with higher status
      • either because east german = more middle class, compressed wage scale
      • pre financial crisis times = more job stability etc.
  • positional deprivation Brian Burgoon et al. (2019)
    • rising share of top 10% Bartels (2019)
    • but not fast rising MW (except for 12 increase, but not much more)
    • lower end of wage scale (feels like down)
    • disappointed by system
    • see inequality
    • inequality => populism
    • ! in (brian?), top income is good for left, while lower decie growth is good for right…
  • additional: instability of job, fear of losing joba nd being unemplyoed ling

Controls

why minimum wage, not general low wage sector

  • of course, MW kind of proxy for low wage sector
  • but is additional psychological (very far end of wage scale)
  • nobody below you (except unemployed)
  • far away from high pay jobs of “winners”

why vote for AfD, not Linke?

  • shown by Bergh and Kärnä (2022), that unemployment = left, insecure job = right
  • Linke = more for privileged voters (piketty)
  • AfD more effective, much attention on them in public discourse

why now, not earlier?

  • party changed attitude towards MW
    • earlier: jobkiller
    • now: important social policy (Grundsatzprogramm)
  • social acceptance of Afd: Exit (Abstention) –> Voice
    • following Hirschman (1972)
  • also: Inflation now hits very hard (2020f)
    • Tober (2022)
    • especially low wage in rural regions

endogeneity: Afd -> MW?

  • not in power anywhere except Sonneberg and small districts
    • MW rise was before
    • not long in power
  • no change in economic structure there

labor market hypothesis?

  • rejected (unemployment share not relevant)
  • but may still have a place as irrational fear

Visualization of Theory:

%%{init: {'theme': "neutral"}}%%
graph LR

A([Financial Crisis]) & B([Austerity]) & C([Trade exposure]) --> MW((Mininum Wage))

A & B & C -.- O[... other Channels]

MW --- D[Lack of mobility] & E[Status Discordance] & F[Positional Deprivation]
--> AfD((Populist voting))
O -.-> AfD

other channels:

eastern germany

  • hard hit by post-Wende turmoil, (Snower and Merkl 2006)
  • creation of Niedriglohnsektor due to TreuHand policy
  • cultural factors as well
  • Mau (2019) vast sociological study (shows difference)

inflation (Tober 2022)

  • hits lower wage workers harder
  • especially rural regions with high share of car dependency

Narrative Case Example: Sonneberg

Conclusion

not stop from higher MW!

Policy

  • union bargaining incerase for higher wages
  • increase social mobility + decrease east west inequality

future Research

  • characteristics of MW jobs
  • panel data set with more than one point in time

References

Alesina, Alberto, Stefanie Stantcheva, and Edoardo Teso. 2018. “Intergenerational Mobility and Preferences for Redistribution.” American Economic Review 108 (2): 521–54. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20162015.
Bartels, Charlotte. 2019. “Top Incomes in Germany, 18712014.” The Journal of Economic History 79 (3): 669–707. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050719000378.
Bergh, Andreas, and Anders Kärnä. 2022. “Explaining the Rise of Populism in European Democracies 19802018: The Role of Labor Market Institutions and Inequality.” Social Science Quarterly 103 (7): 1719–31. https://doi.org/10.1111/ssqu.13227.
Bergman, Matthew E. 2022. “Labour Market Policies and Support for Populist Radical Right Parties: The Role of Nostalgic Producerism, Occupational Risk, and Feedback Effects.” European Political Science Review 14 (4): 520–43. https://doi.org/10.1017/S175577392200025X.
Brian Burgoon, Brian Burgoon, Sam van Noort, S. van Noort, Sam van Noort, Matthijs Rooduijn, Matthijs Rooduijn, Geoffrey R. D. Underhill, and Geoffrey R. D. Underhill. 2019. “Positional Deprivation and Support for Radical Right and Radical Left Parties.” Economic Policy 34 (97): 49–93. https://doi.org/10.1093/epolic/eiy017.
Cantoni, Davide, Felix Hagemeister, and Mark Westcott. 2019. “Persistence and Activation of Right-Wing Political Ideology.” https://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/60795/1/Cantoni_Hagemeister_Persistence_and_Activation_of_Right-Wing_Political_Ideology.pdf.
Dippel, Christian, Robert Gold, Stephan Heblich, and Rodrigo Pinto. 2022. “The Effect of Trade on Workers and Voters.” The Economic Journal 132 (641): 199–217. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueab041.
Dodin, Majed, Sebastian Findeisen, Lukas Henkel, Dominik Sachs, and Paul Schuele. 2021. “Social Mobility in Germany.” {{SSRN Scholarly Paper}}. Rochester, NY. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3892624.
Fischer, Carl Leonard, and Lorenz Meister. 2023. Economic Determinants of Populism.” {Text}. Berlin: DIW Berlin. https://www.diw.de/de/diw_01.c.879785.de/publikationen/roundup/2023_0145/economic_determinants_of_populism.html.
Gabriel, Ricardo Duque, Mathias Klein, and Ana Sofia Pessoa. 2023. “The Political Costs of Austerity.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, September, 1–45. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_01373.
Guriev, Sergei, and Elias Papaioannou. 2022. “The Political Economy of Populism.” Journal of Economic Literature 60 (3): 753–832. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20201595.
Hirschman, Albert O. 1972. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Harvard University Press.
Hövermann, Andreas. 2023. Das Umfragehoch der AFD.” Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliche Institut (WSI). https://www.wsi.de/fpdf/HBS-008748/p_wsi_report_92_2023.pdf.
Kurer, Thomas, and Briitta Van Staalduinen. 2022. “Disappointed Expectations: Downward Mobility and Electoral Change.” American Political Science Review 116 (4): 1340–56. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055422000077.
Mau, Steffen. 2019. Lütten Klein: Leben in der ostdeutschen Transformationsgesellschaft. Suhrkamp Verlag.
Nau, Michael, and Matthew Soener. 2019. “Income Precarity and the Financial Crisis.” Socio-Economic Review 17 (3): 523–44. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwx020.
Pickel, Susanne. 2019. Die Wahl der AfD. Frustration, Deprivation, Angst oder Wertekonflikt? In Die Bundestagswahl 2017: Analysen der Wahl-, Parteien-, Kommunikations- und Regierungsforschung, edited by Karl-Rudolf Korte and Jan Schoofs, 145–75. Wiesbaden: Springer Fachmedien. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-25050-8_7.
Snower, Dennis J., and Christian Merkl. 2006. “The Caring Hand That Cripples: The East German Labor Market After Reunification.” American Economic Review 96 (2): 375–82. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282806777212314.
Tober, Silke. 2022. Haushaltspezifische Teuerungsraten.” IMK Policy Brief, no. 114 (January).
Utar, Hale. 2018. “Workers Beneath the Floodgates: Low-Wage Import Competition and WorkersAdjustment.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 100 (4): 631–47. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00727.
Zavodny, Madeline. 2020. “Political Economy of Minimum Wages.” In Handbook of Labor, Human Resources and Population Economics, edited by Klaus F. Zimmermann, 1–14. Cham: Springer International Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-57365-6_155-1.